Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs

Free Articles

Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an In…nite Horizon Economy Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki NYU and Princeton University May 2012 Abstract We develop a variation of the macroeconomic model of banking in Gertler and Kiyotaki (GK2011) that allows for household liquidity risks and bank runs as in Diamond and Dybvig (DD1983). As in GK, because bank net worth ‡ uctuates with aggregate production, the spread in the expected rates of return on bank credit and deposit ‡ uctuates countercyclically. However, because bank assets have a longer maturity than deposits, bank runs are possible as in DD.

We Will Write a Custom Essay Specifically
For You For Only $13.90/page!


order now

Whether a bank run equilibrium exists depends on the condition of bank balance sheets and an equilibrium liquidation price for bank assets. Thus in normal times a bank run equilibrium may not exist, but the possibility can arise in a severe recession. Overall, the goal is to present a framework that synthesizes the macroeconomic and microeconomic approaches to banking and banking instability. Thanks to Francesco Ferrante and Andrea Prespitino for outstanding research assistance, well above the call of duty. 1 1 Introduction

There are two complementary approaches in the literature to capturing the interaction between banking distress and the real economy. The …rst, summarized recently in Gertler and Kiyotaki (2011), emphasizes how the depletion of bank capital in an economic downturn hinders banks ability to intermediate funds. Due to agency problems (and possibly also regulatory constraints) a bank’ ability to raise funds depends on its capital. Portfolios losses exs perienced in a downturn accordingly lead to losses of bank capital that are increasing in the degree of leverage.

In equilibrium, a contraction of bank capital and bank assets raises the cost of bank credit, slows the economy and depresses asset prices further. The second approach, pioneered by Diamond and Dybvig (1983), focuses on how maturity mismatch in banking, i. e. the combination of short term liabilities and partially illiquid long term assets, opens up the possibility of bank runs. If they occur, runs lead to ine? cient asset liquidation along with a general loss of banking services. In the recent crisis, both phenomena were clearly at work.

Depletion of capital from losses on sub-prime loans and related assets forced many …nancial institutions to contract lending and raised the cost of credit they did o¤er. (See, e. g. Adrian, Colla and Shin, 2012, for example. ) Eventually, however, weakening …nancial positions led to classic runs on a number of the investment banks and money market funds, as emphasized by Gorton (2010) and Bernanke (2010). The asset …resale induced by the runs ampli…ed the overall …nancial distress.

To date, macroeconomic models which have tried to capture the e¤ects of banking distress have emphasized balance-sheet and …nancial accelerator e¤ects, but not captured bank runs. Most models of bank runs, however, are typically quite stylized and not suitable for quantitative analysis. Further, often the runs are not connected to fundamentals. That is, they may be equally likely to occur in good times as well as bad. Our goal is to develop a simple macroeconomic model of banking instability that features both balance-sheet and …nancial accelerator e¤ects and bank runs.

Our approach emphasizes the complementary nature of these mechanisms. Balance sheet conditions not only a¤ect the cost of bank credit, they also a¤ect whether runs are possible. In this respect one can relate the possibility of runs to macroeconomic conditions and in turn characterize how runs feed back into the macroeconomy. For simplicity, we consider an in…nite horizon economy with a …xed supply 2 of capital, along with households and bankers. It is not di? cult to map the framework into a more conventional macroeconomic model with capital accumulation.

The economy with a …xed supply of capital, however, allows us to characterize in a fairly tractable way how banking distress and bank runs a¤ect the behavior of asset prices. With capital accumulation, asset price movements translate into a¤ects on investment and output. As in Gertler and Karadi (2011) and Gertler and Kiyotaki (2011), endogenous procyclical movements in bank balance sheets lead to countercyclical movements in the cost of bank credit. At the same time, due to maturity mismatch, bank runs may be possible, following Diamond and Dybvig (1983).

Whether or not a bank run equilibrium exists will depend on two key factors: the condition of bank balance sheets and an endogenously determined liquidation price. Thus, a situation can arise where a bank run cannot occur in normal times, but where a severe recession can open up the possibility. Critical to the possibility of runs is that banks issues demandable short term debt. In our baseline model we simply assume this is the case. We then provide a stronger motivation for this scenario by introducing household liquidity risks, in the spirit of Diamond and Dybvig.

Section 2 presents the model, including both a no-bank run and a bank run equilibria, along with the extension to the economy with household liquidity risks. Section 3 presents a number of illustrative numerical experiments. We illustrate how bank balance sheet behavior a¤ects the cost of credit in the no-bank run equilibrium and how it may open up the possibility of destructive bank run behavior. Finally, in section 4 we conclude with a discussion of policies that can reduce the likelihood of bank runs. As in Diamond and Dybvig, there is a role for deposit insurance.

However, other possibilities, including commitment by the central bank to lender of last resort activity can also be useful. 2 2. 1 Model Key Features The framework is a variation of the in…nite horizon macroeconomic model with a banking sector and liquidity risks developed in Gertler and Kiyotaki (2011). There are two classes of agents – households and bankers – with a continuum of measure unity of each type. Bankers intermediate funds 3 between households and productive assets. There are two goods, a durable asset “capital,” and a nondurable good.

Capital does not depreciate and is …xed in supply at K which we normalize at unity. We suppose that banks are more e? cient than households at screening and monitoring capital, but we also allow households to directly hold capital as well. Let Ktb be the total capital held by banks and Kth be the amount held by households. Then the allocation of capital must satisfy Ktb + Kth = K = 1: (1) When a banker intermediates Ktb units of capital in period t; there is a payo¤ of Zt+1 Ktb units of the nondurable good in period t + 1 plus the undepreciated leftover capital: date t Ktb capital ! ate t+1 Ktb capital Zt+1 Ktb output (2) where Zt+1 is a multiplicative aggregate shock to productivity. By contrast, we suppose that households that directly hold capital at t for a payo¤ at t + 1 must pay a management cost of f (Kth ) units of the nondurable goods at t; as follows: date t Kth capital f (Kth ) goods ! date t+1 Kth capital Zt+1 Kth output (3) The management cost is meant to re‡ the lack of expertise relative to ect banks that households have in screening and monitoring investment projects.

We suppose that for each household the management cost is increasing and convex in the quantity of capital held: 8 h > (Kth )2 ; for Kth K ; < 2 f (Kth ) = (4) > h h h : K h h K (Kt ); for Kt > K : 2 with > 0: Further, below some threshold K 2 (0; 1) ; f (Kth ) is strictly h convex and then becomes linear after it reaches K : We allow for the kink 4 h in the marginal cost to ensure that it remains pro…table for households to absorb all the capital in the wake of a banking collapse.

In the absence of …nancial market frictions, bankers will intermediate the entire capital stock. In this instance, households save entirely in the form of bank deposits. If the banks are constrained in their ability to obtain funds, households will directly hold some of the capital. Further, to the extent that the constraints on banks tighten countercyclically, as will be the case in our model, the share of capital held by households will move countercyclically. In the extreme case of a bank run, households hold the entire capital stock (i. e. , Kth = 1).

As with virtually all models of banking instability beginning with Diamond and Dybvig (1983), a key to opening up the possibility of a bank run is maturity mismatch. Banks issue non-contingent short term liabilities and hold imperfectly liquid long term assets. Within our framework, the combination of …nancing constraints on banks and ine? ciencies in household management of capital will give rise to imperfect liquidity in the market for capital. We proceed to describe the behavior of households, banks and the competitive equilibrium. We then describe the circumstances under which bank runs are possible.

For expositional purposes, we begin by studying a benchmark model where we simply assume that banks issues short term debt. Within this benchmark model we can illustrate the main propositions regarding the possibility of bank runs and the connection to bank balance sheet strength. We then generalize the model to allow for household liquidity risks in the spirit of Diamond and Dybvig in order to motivate why banks issue demandable deposits. 2. 2 Households Each household consumes and saves. Households save by either by lending funds to competitive …nancial intermediaries or by holding capital directly.

In addition to the returns on portfolio investments, each household also receives an endowment of nondurable goods, Zt W h , every period that varies proportionately with the aggregate productivity shock Zt : Intermediary deposits held from t to t + 1 are one period bonds that pay the certain gross return Rt+1 in the absence of a bank run. In the event of a bank run, a depositor may receive either the full promised return or nothing, depending on the timing of the withdrawal. Following Diamond and Dybvig 5 (1983), we suppose that deposits are paid out according to a “sequential service constraint. Depositors form a line to withdraw and the bank meets the obligation sequentially until its funds are exhausted. If the bank has insu? cient funds to meet its withdrawal requests, a fraction of depositors will be left with nothing. We assume that bank runs are completely unanticipated events. Thus, we proceed to solve the household’ choice problem as if it s perceives no possibility of a bank run. Then in a subsequent section we characterize the circumstances under which an unanticipated run might be possible. Let Cth be household consumption, Dt be household bank deposits, and Qt be the market price of capital.

Household utility Ut is given by ! 1 X i h Ut = Et ln Ct+i i=0 with 0 < < 1: The household then chooses consumption Cth , direct capital holdings Kth and bank deposits Dt to maximize expected utility subject to the budget constraint Cth + Dt + Qt Kth + f (Kth ) = Zt W h + Rt Dt 1 + (Zt + Qt )Kth 1 ; where, again, we assume that the household assigns a zero probability of a bank run. The …rst order conditions for deposits and direct capital holdings are given by Et ( t;t+1 Rt+1 ) = 1 (5) Et ( where t;t+i h t;t+1 Rkt+1 ) =1 (6) = i Cth h Ct+i (7) h h Rt+1 = h Zt+1 + Qt+1 Qt + f 0 (Kth ) h nd f 0 (Kth ) = Kth for Kth (0; K ] and = K for Kth [K ; 1]: t;t+i is the household’ marginal rate of intertemporal substitution between consumption s h at date t + i and t, and Rt+1 is the household’ gross marginal rate of return s from direct capital holdings. 6 Observe that so long as the household has at least some direct capital holdings, the …rst order condition (6) will help determine the market price of capital. Further, the market price of capital tends to be decreasing in h the share of capital held by households given that over the range (0; K ], the marginal management cost f 0 (Kth ) is increasing.

As will become clear, a banking crisis will induce asset sales by banks to households, leading a drop in asset prices. The severity of the drop will depend on the quantity of sales and the convexity of the management cost function. In the limiting case of a bank run households absorb all the capital from banks. Capital prices will h reach minimum as the marginal cost reaches a maximum (at K ). Given the utility speci…cation, one can combine the …rst order conditions with the budget constraint to obtain the following solutions for household consumption Cth = (1 where Ft = Zt W h + f 0 (Kth )Kth f Kth + Et ( t;t+1 Ft+1 ): R t Dt 1 + (Zt + Qt )Kth 1 + Ft (8) (9) Households consume the fraction 1 of total wealth: Here; Ft is the present value of sum of the endowment of nondurable goods and ’ pro…ts’from direct capital holdings, measured as the gap between the marginal management cost times direct capital holdings and the total management cost. 2. 3 Banks Each banker manages a …nancial intermediary. Bankers fund capital investments by issuing deposits to households as well as by using their own equity, or net worth, nt . Due to …nancial market frictions, bankers may be constrained n their ability to obtain deposits from households. To the extent bankers may face …nancial market frictions, they will attempt to save their way out of the …nancing constraint by accumulating retained earnings in order to move toward one hundred percent equity …nancing. To limit this possibility, we assume that bankers have …nite expected horizons. In particular, we suppose that each banker has an i. i. d probability of surviving until the next period and a probability 1 of exiting. The expected horizon of a banker is then 1 1 : Note that the expected horizon may be long. But it is critical that it is …nite. 7

Every period new bankers enter: The number of entering bankers equals the number who exit, keeping the total population of bankers constant. Each new banker takes over the enterprise of an exiting banker and in the process inherits the skills of the exiting banker. The exiting banker removes his equity stake nt in the bank. The new banker’ initial equity stake consists s b an endowment w of nondurable goods received only in the …rst period of operation. As will become clear, this setup provides a simple way to motivate “dividend payouts” from the banking system in order to ensure that banks use leverage in equilibrium.

In particular, we assume that bankers are risk neutral and enjoy utility from consumption in the period they exit. 1 Let cb be terminal consumption t by an individual banker. Then the expected utility of a continuing banker at the end of period t is given by “1 # X i Vt = Et (1 ) i 1 cb t+i : i=1 b During each period t a bank …nances its asset holdings Qt kt with deposits dt and net worth nt : b Qt kt = dt + nt : (10) We assume that banks cannot issue new equity: They can only accumulate net worth via retained earnings.

While this assumption approximately accords with reality, we do not explicitly model the agency frictions that underpin it. The net worth of “surviving” bankers is the gross return on assets net the cost of deposits, as follows: b nt = (Zt + Qt )kt 1 Rt dt 1 : (11) For new bankers at t, net worth simply equals the initial endowment: nt = w b : Finally, exiting bankers no longer operate banks and simply use their net worth to consume: cb = n t : t We could generalize to allow active bankers to receive utility that is linear in consumption each period.

So long as the banker is constrained, it will be optimal to defer all consumption until the exit period. 1 8 To motivate a limit on the bank’ ability to obtain deposits, we introduce s the following moral hazard problem: At the end of the period the banker can choose to divert the fraction of assets for personal use. (Think of the way a banker may divert funds is by paying unwarranted bonuses or dividends to his or her family members. ) The cost to the banker is that the depositors can force the intermediary into bankruptcy at the beginning of the next period.

The depositors can only recover the fraction of 1 of the assets from the defaulting bank. Accordingly, for rational depositors to lend, it must be the case that the franchise value of the bank, i. e. , the present discounted value of payouts from operating the bank, Vt , exceeds the gain to the bank from diverting assets. Accordingly, any …nancial arrangement between the bank and its depositors must satisfy the following incentive constraint2 : b Qt kt Vt : (12)

Given that bankers simply consume their equity when they exit, we can restate the bank’ franchise value recursively as the expected discounted value s of net worth at the time of exiting, as follows: Vt = Et [ (1 )nt+1 + Vt+1 ]: (13) b The banker’ optimization problem then is to choose kt ; dt each period to s maximize the franchise value (13) subject to the incentive constraint (12) and the ‡ of funds constraints (10,11). ow We guess that the bank’ franchise value is the linear function of assets s and deposits as follows b Vt = kt kt t dt ; and then subsequently verify this guess.

Using the ‡ ow-of-funds constraint (10) ; we can express the franchise value as: Vt = with t 2 b t Qt kt + t nt kt Qt t: Note that the incentive constraint embeds the constraint that nt must be positive for the bank to operate since Vt will turn out to be linear in nt : We will choose parameters and shock variances that keep nt non-negative in a “no-bank run” equilibrium. An unanticipated bank run, however, will force nt to zero, as we show later. 9 We can think of t as the excess marginal dollar value of assets over deposits. In turn, we can rewrite the incentive constraint as b Qt kt b t Qt kt t nt : It follows that incentive constraint (12) is binding if and only if the excess marginal value from honestly managing assets t is positive but less than the marginal gain from diverting assets ; i. e. 3 0< t < : Assuming this condition is satis…ed, the incentive constraint leads to the b following limit on the scale of bank assets Qt kt to net worth nt : b Qt kt = nt t t t: (14) We refer to t as the maximum leverage ratio. It depends inversely on ; An increase in the bank’ ability to divert funds reduces the amount deposis tors are willing to lend.

As the bank expands assets by issuing deposits, its incentive to divert funds increases. The constraint (14) limits the portfolio size to the point where the bank’ incentive to cheat is exactly balanced by s the cost of losing the franchise value. In this respect the agency problem leads to an endogenous capital constraint. From equations (10) and (11); the recursive expression of franchise value (13) becomes b t Qt kt + t nt = Et 1 + t+1 + t+1 t+1 b (Rt+1 b Rt+1 )Qt kt + Rt+1 nt ; b where Rt+1 is the realized rate of return on banks assets (i. e. apital intermediated by bank), and is given by b Rt+1 = Zt+1 + Qt+1 : Qt Using the method of undetermined coe? cients, we verify the conjecture that the franchise value is indeed linear in assets and deposits, with t 3 b = Et [(Rt+1 Rt+1 ) t+1 ]; (15) In the numerical analysis in section 3, we choose parameters to ensure that the condition 0 < t < is always satis…ed in the no bank-run equilibrium. 10 t = Rt+1 Et ( t+1 ) (16) with t+1 1 + t+1 + t+1 t+1 : The coe? cient t is the discounted excess return per unit of assets intermediated. The coe? cient t is the discounted cost per unit of deposits.

In each case the payo¤s are adjusted by the variable t+1 which takes into account that, if the bank is constrained, the shadow value of a unit of net worth to the bank may exceed unity. In particular, we can think of t+1 as a probability weighted average of the marginal values of net worth to exiting and to continuing bankers at t+1. For an exiting banker at t + 1 (which occurs with probability 1 ; the shadow value of an additional unit of net worth is simply unity, since he or she just consumes it. Conversely, for a continuing banker (which occurs with probability ), the shadow value is b @Vt =@nt = t + t (@Qt kt =@nt ) = t + t t .

In this instance an additional unit of net worth saves the banker t in deposit costs and permits he or she to earn the excess value t on an additional t units of assets, the latter being the amount of assets he can lever with an additional unit of net worth. When the incentive constraint is not binding, unlimited arbitrage by banks will push discounted excess returns to zero, implying t = 0: When the incentive constraint is binding, however, limits to arbitrage emerge that lead to positive expected excess returns in equilibrium, i. . , t > 0: Note that the excess return to capital implies that for a given riskless interest rate, the required return to capital is higher than would otherwise be and, conversely the price of capital is lower. Indeed, a …nancial crisis in the model will involve a sharp increase in the excess rate of returns on asset along with a sharp contraction in the price of asset. In this regards, a bank run will be an extreme version of a …nancial crisis. 2. 4 Aggregation and Equilibrium without Bank Runs

Given that the maximum feasible leverage ratio t is independent of individualspeci…c factors and given a parametrization where the incentive constraint is binding in equilibrium, we can aggregate across banks to obtain the relation between total assets held by the banking system Qt Ktb and total net worth Nt : Qt Ktb = t Nt : (17) 11 Summing across both surviving and entering bankers yields the following expression for the evolution of Nt : Nt = [(Zt + Qt )Ktb 1 Rt Dt 1 ] + W b (18) where W b = (1 )wb is the total endowment of entering bankers.

The …rst term is the accumulated net worth of bankers that operated at t 1 and survived to t, equal to the product of the survival rate and the net earnings on bank assets (Zt + Qt )Ktb 1 Rt Dt 1 : Conversely, exiting bankers consume the fraction 1 of net earnings on assets: Ctb = (1 )[(Zt + Qt )Ktb 1 Rt Dt 1 ]: (19) Total output Yt is the sum of output from capital, household endowment Zt W h and bank endowment W b : Yt = Z t + Z t W h + W b : (20) Finally, output is either used for management costs, or consumed by households and bankers: Yt = f (Kth ) + Cth + Ctb : (21) 2. 5 Bank Runs

We now consider the possibility of an unexpected bank run. In particular, we maintain assumption that when households acquire deposits at t 1 that mature in t; they attach zero probability to a possibility of a run at t: However, we now allow for the chance of a run ex post, as deposits mature at t and households must decide whether to roll them over for another period. An ex post “run equilibrium” is possible if individual depositors believe that if other households do not roll over their deposits with the bank, the bank may not be able to meet its obligations on the remaining deposits.

As in Diamond and Dybvig (1983), the sequential service feature of deposit contracts opens up the possibility that a depositor could lose everything by failing to withdraw. In this situation two equilibria are possible: a “normal” one where households keep their deposits in banks, and a “run” equilibrium where households withdraw all their deposits, banks are liquidated, and households use their residual funds to acquire capital directly. 12 We begin with the standard case where each depositor decides whether to run, before turning to a more quantitatively ‡ exible case where at any moment only a fraction of depositors consider running. . 5. 1 Conditions for a Bank Run Equilibrium In particular, at the beginning of period t; before the realization of returns on bank assets, depositors decide whether to roll over their deposits with the bank. If they choose to “run”, the bank liquidates its capital and turns the proceeds over to households who then acquire capital directly with their less e? cient technology. Let Qt be the price of capital in the event of a forced liquidation. Then a run is possible if the liquidation value of bank assets (Zt + Qt )Ktb 1 is smaller than its outstanding liability to the depositors:4 (Zt + Qt )Ktb 1 lt; R t Dt 1 : (22) If condition (22) is satis…ed, an individual depositor who does not withdraw su? ciently early could lose everything in the even of run. If any one depositor faces this risk, then they all do, which makes a run equilibrium feasible. If the inequality is reversed, banks can always meet their obligations to depositors, meaning that runs cannot occur in equilibrium. 5 The condition determining the possibility of a bank run depends on two key endogenous variables, the liquidation price of capital Qt and the condition of bank balance sheets.

Combining the bank funding constraint (10) with (22) implies we can restate the condition for a bank run equilibrium as (Zt + Qt Rt Qt 1 )Ktb 1 + R t Nt 1 < 0: This condition states that a bank run is possible if depositors perceive that conditional on liquidation of assets, net worth of the bank system would be negative. We can rearrange this to obtain a simple condition for a bank run equilibrium in terms of just three variables: b Rt 4 Zt + Qt < Rt (1 Qt 1 1 t 1 ) (23) Since banks are homogenous in n; the conditions for a run on the system are the same as for a run on any individual bank. We assume that there is a small cost of running to the bank, and that households will not run if their bank will pay the promised deposit return for sure. 13 where t 1 is the bank leverage ratio at t 1: A bank run equilibrium is b more likely the lower the realized rate of return on bank assets Rt relative to the gross interest rate on deposits Rt and the higher is the leverage ratio. 1 ) is the ratio of bank deposits Dt 1 to bank Note that the expression (1 t 1 b capital Qt 1 Kt 1 , which is increasing in the leverage ratio. Since Rt ; Rt and t are all endogenous variables, the possibility of a bank run may vary with macroeconomic conditions. The equilibrium absent bank runs (that we described earlier) determines the behavior of Rt and t : The b behavior of Rt is increasing in the liquidation price Qt ; which depends on the behavior of the economy. Finally, we now turn to a more ‡ exible case that we use in the quantitative analysis, where at each time t only a fraction of depositors consider running. Here the idea is that not all depositors are su? iently alert to market conditions to contemplate running. This scenario is consistent with evidence that during a run only a fraction of depositors actually try to quickly withdraw. In this situation, a run is possible if any individual depositor who is considering a run perceives the bank cannot meet the obligations of the group that could potentially withdraw. Thus, assuming individual depositors who might run know , a run is possible if the following condition is satis…ed (Zt + Qt )Ktb 1 < Rt Dt 1 which, proceeding as before, can be expressed as b Rt < Rt (1 1 t 1 ): (24)

Thus, in the condition for the possibility of a bank run equilibrium, the deposit rate is adjusted by the fraction of depositors who could potentially run. 2. 5. 2 The Liquidation Price To determine Qt we proceed as follows. A depositor run at t induces all banks that carried assets from t 1 to fully liquidate their asset positions and go out of business. New banks do not enter. Given our earlier assumption that new bankers can operate only by taking over functioning franchises of 14 exiting bankers, the collapse of existing banks eliminates the possibility of transferring the necessary skill and apparatus to new bankers. Accordingly, when banks liquidate, they sell all their assets to households. In the wake of the run at date t and for each period after, accordingly: h 1 = Kt+i ; for all i 0; (25) where, again, unity is the total supply of capital. Further, since banks no longer are operating, entering bankers simply consume their respective endowments: Ctb = W b : The consumption of households is then the sum of their endowment and the returns on their capital net of management costs: Cth = Zt W h + Zt f (1) (26) here the last term on the right is household portfolio management costs, which are at a maximum in this instance given that the household is directly holding the entire capital stock. h s Let Rt+1 be the household’ marginal return on capital from t to t + 1 when banks have collapsed at t. Then the …rst order condition for household direct capital holding is given by Et f with h Rt+1 = h h t;t+1 Rt+1 g =1 Zt+1 + Qt+1 Qt + K h where K is the marginal portfolio management cost when households are absorbing all the capital (see equation (4)). Rearranging yields the following This assumption is for purely technical reasons: It makes the liquidation price easy to calculate. If we allowed new banks to enter, (under any reasonable calibration), the banking system would eventually recover, but it would be a very long and slow process. Under either approach, the near term behavior of liquidation prices would be simiar. 7 When there are bank runs at date t, consumption and saving on capital and deposit are di¤erent across households, depending upon the timing of withdrawal. But we consider that each household pays the same management fee ( K) for every unit of capital purchase.

The pro…t of management company K f (1) is distributed to all the households lump sum as in (9) . Then the marginal rate of substitution t;t+i is the same across households. 6 15 expression for the liquidation price in terms of discounted dividends net the marginal management cost. “1 # X h h Qt = Et K ) K : (27) t;t+i (Zt+i i=1 Everything else equal, the higher the marginal management cost the lower the liquidation price. Note Qt as well as t will vary with cyclical conditions. Thus, even if a bank run equilibrium does not exist in the neighborhood of the no-run steady state, it is possible that a su? iently negative disturbance to the economy could open up this possibility. We illustrate this point in Section 3 below. Finally, we observe that within our framework the distinction between a liquidity shortage and insolvency is more subtle than is often portrayed in popular literature. If a bank run equilibrium exists, banks become insolvent, i. e. their liabilities exceed their assets if assets are valued at the …re-sale price Qt . But if assets are valued at the price in the no-run equilibrium Qt ; the banks are all solvent.

Thus whether banks are insolvent or not depends upon equilibrium asset prices which in turn depend on the liquidity in the banking system; and this liquidity can change abruptly in the event of a run. As a real world example of this phenomenon consider the collapse of the banking system during the Great Depression. As Friedman and Schwartz (1963) point out that, what was initially a liquidity problem in the banking system (due in part by inaction of the Fed), turned into a solvency problem as runs on banks led to a collapse in long-term security prices and in the banking system along with it. . 6 Household liquidity risks Up to this point we have simply assumed that banks engage in maturity mismatch by issuing non-contingent one period deposits despite holding risky long maturity assets. We now motivate why banks might issue liquid short term deposits. In the spirit of Diamond and Dybvig (1983), we do so by introducing idiosyncratic household liquidity risks, which creates a desire by households for demandable debt.

We do not derive these types of deposits from an explicit contracting exercise. However, we think that a scenario with liquidity moves us one step closer to understanding why banks issue liquid deposits despite having partially illiquid assets. 16 As before, we assume that there is a continuum of measure unity of households. To keep the heterogeneity introduced by having independent liquidity risks manageable, we further assume that each household consists of a continuum of unit measure individual members.

Each member of the representative household has a need for emergency expenditures within the period with probability . At the same time, because the household has a continuum of members, exactly the fraction has a need for emergency consumption. In particular, let cm be emergency expenditures by an individual member, t with cm = Ctm being the total emergency expenditures by the family. For t an individual with emergency expenditures needs, period utility is given by log Cth + log cm ; t where Cth is regular consumption.

For family members that do not need to make emergency expenditures, period utility is given simply by log Cth : Because they are sudden, emergency expenditures must be made with demandable bank debt, in a way that we make clear shortly. We suppose that demand deposits at banks are necessary to make emergency expenditures. To keep things simple, we suppose that the members of a household must buy endowment from other households which can be transformed to cm : Conversely the household sells endowment that can be t converted to cm to other families in return for deposits. The timing of events is as follows: At the beginning of period t; before the realization of the liquidity risk at the end of t, the household chooses Cth and the allocation of its portfolio between bank deposits Dt and directly held h capital Kt: : The household plans the date-t regular consumption to be the same for every member since all members of the household are identical ex ante and utility is separable in Cth and cm . After choosing the total level of t deposits, the household divides them evenly amongst it members.

Entering period t, an individual has access only to his or her own deposits at the time the liquidity risk is realized. Those having to make emergency expenditures above some threshold cm must …nance them from funds in their deposits accounts at the beginning of t;8 cm t 8 cm Dt : (28) One can think each member carrying a deposit certi…cate of the amount Dt . Each 17 Think of cm as the amount of emergency expenditure that can be arranged through credit as opposed to deposits. 9 After the realization of the liquidity shock, individuals with excess deposits simply return them to the household.

The next sequence of optimization then begins at the beginning of period t + 1. 10 We can express the formal decision problem of the household with liquidity risks as follows: Ut (Dt 1 ; Kth 1 ) = max f(log Cth + log cm + Et [Ut+1 (Dt ; Kth )]g t h h Ct ;cm ;Dt ;Kt t subject to the budget constraint Cth + cm + Dt + Qt Kth + f (Kth ) = Rt Dt t 1 + (Zt + Qt )Kth 1 + Zt W h (29) and the liquidity constraint given by (28). Let t be the Lagrangian multiplier on the liquidity constraint. Then the …rst order conditions for deposits Dt and emergency expenditures are given by: Et f t;t+1 Rt+1 g t 1=Cth t: = 1; (30) (31) cm t 1 = Cth The multiplier on the liquidity constraint t is equal to the gap between the marginal utility of emergency consumption and regular consumption for a household member who experiences a liquidity shock. Observe that if the liquidity constraint binds, there is a relative shortage of the liquid asset, which pushes down the deposit rate, everything else equal, as equation (30) suggests. further of unable to make use of the deposit certi…cates of the other members of the family for his or her emergency consumption.

Although an individual member may use up the deposit certi…cate, the family’ total deposits at the end of period is equal to the initial s level, because the out‡ of funds is balanced with the in‡ of funds by a law of a large ow ow number as long as the budget constraint (equation (29) below) is satis…ed. 9 We allow for cm so that households can make some emergency expenditures in a bank run equilibrium, which keeps the marginal utility of cm from going to in…nity in this case. 0 Since deposits are pooled after the realization of the liquidity shock we do not have to keep track of the history of this shock on individual wealth. 18 The …rst order condition for the households choice of direct capital holding is the same as in the case without liquidity risks (see equation (6)). The decision problem for banks is also the same, as are the conditions for aggregate bank behavior. In the aggregate (and after using the bank funding condition to eliminate deposits), the liquidity constraint becomes: Ctm cm (Qt Ktb Nt ):

Given that households are now making emergency expenditures, the relation for uses of output becomes Yt = Cth + Ctm + Ctb + f (Kth ): (32) Otherwise, the remaining equations that determine the equilibrium without liquidity risks (absent bank runs) also applies in this case. Importantly the condition for a bank run (equation 23) also remains unchanged. The determination of the liquidation price is also e¤ectively the same (see equation 27). There is one minor change, however: The calculation of Qt is slightly di¤erent since households are now making emergency expenditures cm ; in addition to consuming Cth : t Numerical Examples Our goal here is to provide some suggestive numerical examples to illustrate the workings of the model. Speci…cally we construct an example where a recession tightens bank balance sheet constraints, which leads to an “excessive” drop in asset prices and opens up the possibility of a bank run. We then illustrate the e¤ects of an unanticipated run. We …rst present results for our baseline model and then do the same for the model with liquidity risks. 3. 1 Parameter Choices

Table 1 lists the choice of parameter values for our baseline model, while Table 2 gives the steady state values of the endogenous variables. Overall there are nine key parameters in the baseline model and an additional two in the model with liquidity risks. Two parameters in the baseline are 19 conventional: the quarterly discount factor which we set at 0:99 and the serial correlation of the productivity shock Zt which we set at 0:95. Seven h parameters ( ; ; W b ; ; K ; ; W h ) are speci…c to our model. Our choice of these parameters is meant to be suggestive.

We set the banker’ survival s probability equal to 0:93 which implies an expected horizon of three and half years. We choose values for the seizure rate parameter , the banker’ s b initial endowment W , and the “management cost parameter to hit the following targets in the steady state absent bank runs: a bank leverage ratio of eight, the annual spread between the the expected return on capital and the riskless rate of 240 basis points, and a steady state allocation of capital holdings such direct holdings by the household are small, e. g. , roughly …ve h percent.

We set K based on two considerations: It is high enough so that Kth within a local region of the steady state stays below it (so we can use loglinear numerical methods within a local region of the steady state in the no run case). At the same time it is low enough to ensure that households …nd it pro…table to directly hold capital in the bank run equilibrium. Finally, we set the fraction of depositors who may run at any moment to 0:7, which makes it feasible to have a steady state without a bank run equilibrium with the possibility of a run equilibrium in the recession.

We set the household steady state endowment ZW h (which roughly corresponds to labor income) to three times steady state capital income Z: We also normalize the steady state price of a unit of capital Qt at unity, which restricts the steady value of Zt (which determined output stream from capital). Finally, for the model with liquidity risks we use the same parametrization as in our baseline case.

There are, however, three additional parameters ( ; ; cm ): We choose these parameters to ensure that (i) the steady spread between the households net return on capital Rh and the deposit R rate is …fty basis points at an annual level, and (ii) households can still makes some emergency expenditures in an bank run equilibrium. For all other parameters, we use the same values as in the baseline case with one exception: we adjust the fraction of depositors who may run so that the steady state cost per deposit to the bank in the event of a run, R is the same as in the baseline case. 1 Roughly speaking, for a given set of parameter values, this makes the likelihood of a run within a local region of the steady state the same in both cases. 11 The liquidity premium makes R lower in the case with liquidity risks than in the baseline case, which everything else equal, makes the likliehood of a run lower. 20 3. 2 Recessions, Banking Distress and Bank Runs: Some Simulations We have parametrized the model so that a bank run equilibrium does not exist in the steady state but could arise if the economy enters a recession.

We begin by analyzing the response of the economy to a negative shock to Zt assuming the economy stays in the “no bank run” equilibrium. We then examine the e¤ects of an unanticipated bank run, once the economy enters a region where runs are possible. For each case we …rst examine the baseline model and then turn to the model with liquidity risks. Figure 1 shows the response of the baseline model to an unanticipated negative …ve percent shock to productivity, Zt : This leads to a drop in output of roughly …ve percent, a magnitude which is characteristic of a major recession.

Though a bank run does not arise in this case, the recession induces …nancial distress that ampli…es the contraction in assets prices and raises the cost of bank credit. The unanticipated drop in Zt reduces net worth Nt which tightens bank balance sheets, leading to a contraction of bank deposits and a …resale of bank assets, which in turn magni…es the asset price decline. Households absorb some of the asset, but because this is costly for them, the amount they acquire is limited.

The net e¤ect is a substantial increase in the cost of bank credit: the spread between the required expected return to bank assets and the riskless rate increases one hundred and …fty basis points on impact. Overall, the recession induces the kind of bank balance sheet/…nancial accelerator mechanism prevalent in Gertler and Kiyotaki (2011) and other macroeconomic models of bank distress. Figure 2 repeats the same experiment as in Figure 1, this time examining the model with liquidity risks. The overall impact on the asset price and the cost of bank credit is similar to the baseline case.

One interesting di¤erence, however, is that unlike the baseline, there is a sharper drop in the deposit interest rates relative to the baseline. In the baseline, the deposit interest rate drops one hundred basis points on impact. In this case, the drop is almost four times as much as the baseline for two reasons. First, the contraction in bank deposits raises the liquidity premium for deposits, which increases the h spread between the expected rate of return on household’ capital Et (Rt+1 ) s h and the deposit rate.

Second, Et (Rt+1 ) drops by more in the baseline model as households now smooth the decline in Cth as they cut back sharply on 21 Ctm :12 We now allow for the possibility of bank runs. To determine whether a bank equilibrium exists, we …rst de…ne Qt as the threshold value of the liquidation price below which a bank run equilibrium exists. It follows from equation (24) that Qt is given by Qt = Rt (1 1 t 1 )Qt 1 Zt : (33) Note that Qt is increasing in t 1 , which implies that everything else equal a bank run equilibrium is more likely the higher is bank leverage at t 1.

We next construct a variable called “run” that is the di¤erence between Qt and the liquidation price Qt : runt = Qt Qt : (34) A bank run equilibrium exists i¤ runt > 0: In the steady of our model run < 0, implying a bank run equilibrium does not exist in this situation. However, the recession opens up the possibility of runt > 0, by simultaneously raising Qt and lowering Qt . Figure 3 revisits the recession experiment for the baseline model, this time allowing for a bank run ex post. The …rst panel of the middle row shows that the run variable becomes positive upon impact and remains positive for roughly ten quarters.

An unanticipated bank run is thus possible at any point in this interval. The reason the bank run equilibrium exists is that the negative productivity shock reduces the liquidation price Qt and leads to an increase in the bank’ leverage ratio t (as bank net worth declines relative s to assets). Both these factors work to make the banking system vulnerable to a run, as equations (33) and (34) indicate. In Figure 3 we suppose an unanticipated run occurs in the second period after the shock. The solid line portrays the bank run while the dotted line tracks the no-bank run equilibrium for reference.

The run produces a complete liquidation of bank assets as Ktb drops to zero. The asset price falls to it liquidation price which is roughly forty percent below the steady state. Output net of household capital management costs drops roughly twenty percent. 12 h Ct : h From the household’ Euler equation, Et (Rt+1 ) depends positively on the growth of s 22 The high management costs arise because in the absence of the banking system, households are directly holding the entire capital stock. The reduction of net output implies that household consumption drops roughly ten percent on impact.

Bankers consumption drops nearly to zero as existing bankers are completely wiped out and new bankers are only able to consume their endowment. Finally, Figure 4 repeats the experiment for the model with liquidity risks. The behavior of the economy in the wake of a bank run is very similar to the baseline case. One di¤erence is that the time interval over which a bank run equilibrium is possible is shorter. This occurs because the drop in the deposit rate following the recessionary shock is greater than in the baseline case (see Figure 2) which reduces the likelihood that the conditions for a bank run equilibrium will be met. Conclusion We end with some remarks about government …nancial policy. As in Diamond and Dybvig (1983) the existence of the bank run equilibrium introduces a role for deposit insurance. The belief that deposits will be insured eliminates the incentive to run in our framework just as it does in the original Diamond/Dybvig setup. If all goes well, further, the deposit insurance need never be used in practice. By being available, it serves its purpose simply by ruling out beliefs that could lead to a bank run.

Of course, as is well understood, moral hazard considerations (not present in our current framework) could produce negative side e¤ects from deposit insurance. The solution used in practice is to combine capital requirements with deposit insurance. As many authors have pointed out, capital requirements help o¤set the incentives for risk-taking that deposit insurance induces. Within our framework, capital requirements have an added bene…t: they reduce the size of the region where bank run equilibria are feasible.

This occurs because the possibility of a bank run equilibrium is increasing in the leverage ratio. If equity capital is costly for banks to raise, as appears to be the case in practice, then capital requirements may also have negative side e¤ects. A number of authors have recently pointed that the “stabilizing” e¤ects of capital requirements may be countered to some degree by the increased cost of intermediation (to the extent raising equity capital is costly). Our model suggests that a commitment by the central bank to lender of 23 last resort policies may also be useful.

Within our framework the endogenously determined liquidation price of bank assets is a key determinant of whether a bank run equilibrium exists. In this regard, a commitment to use lender of last resort policies to support liquidation prices could be useful. For example, central bank asset purchases that support the secondary market prices of bank assets might be e¤ective in keeping liquidation prices su? ciently high to rule out the possibility of runs. (Consider the recent purchases by the Federal Reserve of agency mortgaged-backed securities, in the wake of the collapse of the shadow banking system. An issue to investigate is whether by signalling the availability of such a tool in advance of the crisis, the central bank might have been able to reduce the likelihood of runs on the shadow banks ex post. Gertler and Karadi (2011) and Gertler and Kiyotaki (2011) explore the use of this kind of policy tool in a macroeconomic model of banking distress but without bank runs. 13 It would be useful to extend the analysis of this policy tool and related lender of last resort policies to a setting with bank runs. 3 See also Gertler, Kiyotaki and Queralto (2011) which takes into account the moral hazard e¤ects of lender of last resort policies by endogenizing the risk of bank liability structure. 24 References [1] Adrian, T. , Colla, P. , and Shin, H. , 2012. Which Financial Frictions? Paring the Evidence from Financial Crisis of 2007-9. Forthcoming in NBER Macroeconomic Annual. [2] Allen, F. , and Gale, D. , 2007. Understanding Financial Crises. Oxford University Press. [3] Bernanke, B. , 2010. Causes of the Recent Financial and Economic Crisis. Statement before the Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission, Washington, September 2. 4] Bernanke, B. , and Gertler, M. , 1989. Agency Costs, Net Worth and Business Fluctuations. American Economic Review 79, 14-31. [5] Bigio, S. , 2012. Financial Risk Capacity. Mimeo, NYU. [6] Brunnermeier, M. K. , and Sannikov, Y. , 2011. A Macroeconomic Model with a Financial Sector. Mimeo, Princeton University. [7] Brunnermeier, M. K. , and Oehmke, M. , 2012.. Bubbles, Financial Crises and Systemic Risk. Mimeo, Princeton University. [8] Calomiris, C. , and Kahn, C. , 1991. The Role of Demandable Debt in Structuring Banking Arrangements. American Economic Review 81, 497-513. 9] Diamond, D. , and Dybvig, P. , 1983. Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity. Journal of Political Economy 91, 401-419. [10] Diamond, D. , and Rajan, R. , 2000. A Theory of Bank Capital, Journal of Finance.. [11] Friedman, M. , and Schwartz, A. , 1963. A Monetary History of the United States, 1867-1960. Princeton University Press. [12] Gertler, M. , and Karadi, P. , 2011. A Model of Unconventional Monetary Policy, Journal of Monetary Economics, January. 25 [13] Gertler, M. , and Kiyotaki, N. , 2010. Financial Intermediation and Credit Policy in Business Cycle Analysis.

In Friedman, B. , and Woodford, M. (Eds. ), Handbook of Monetary Economics. Elsevier, Amsterdam, Netherlands. [14] Gertler, M. , Kiyotaki, N. , and Queralto, A. , 2011. Financial Crises, Bank Risk Exposure and Government Financial Policy. Mimeo, NYU and Princeton University. [15] Gilchrist, S. , Yankov, V. , and Zakrasjek, E. , 2009. Credit Market Shocks and Economic Fluctuations: Evidence from Corporate Bond and Stock Markets. Mimeo, Boston University. [16] Gorton, G. , 2010. Slapped by the Invisible Hand: The Panic of 2007. Oxford University Press. [17] He. Z. and A. Krishnamurthy, 2012.

Intermediary Asset Pricing. Mimeo, Northwestern University. [18] Holmstrom, B. and J. Tirole, 1997. Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds, and the Real Sector. Quarterly Journal of Economics 112, 663692. [19] Kiyotaki, N. , and Moore, J. , 1997. Credit Cycles. Journal of Political Economy 105, 211-248. [20] Martin, A. , D. Skeie and E. L. Von Thadden. Repo Runs. Mimeo, Federal Reserve Bank of New York. [21] Roch, Francisco and Harald Uhlig, 2012. The Dynamics of Sovereign Debt Crises in a Monetary Union. Mimeo, University of Chicago. 26 Table 1: Parameters Baseline Model 0. 99 Discount rate 0. 5 Bankers survival probability 0. 35 Seizure rate 0. 1 Household managerial cost K h 0. 096 Threshold capital for managerial cost 0. 72 Fraction of depositors that can run 0. 95 Serial correlation of productivity shock 0. 0161 Steady state productivity Z ! b 0. 0019 Bankers endowment 0. 045 Household endowment ! h Additional Parameters for Liquidity Model 62. 67 Preference weight on cm 0. 01 Threshold for cm cm 0. 03 Probability of a liquidity shock 0. 67 Fraction of depositors that can run L 1 Table 2: Steady State Values Steady State for No Bank-Run Equilibrium Baseline Liquidity K 1 1 Q 1 1 Ch 0. 541 0. 0184 Cm 0 0. 0348 Cb 0. 0087 0. 0088 Kh 0. 0594 0. 0545 0. 9406 0. 9455 Kb 8 8 Rb 1. 0644 1. 0624 1. 0404 1. 0404 Rh R 1. 0404 1. 0384 Steady State for Bank-Run Equilibrium Baseline Liquidity K 1 1 Q 0. 6340 1 0. 0520 0. 0515 Ch Cm 0 0. 01 0. 0019 0. 0019 Cb Kh 1 1 0 0 Kb Rb Rh R 1. 1016 1. 0404 1. 1068 1. 0404 2 Figure 1: A Recession in the Baseline Model: No Bank Run Case 1 Figure 2: A Recession in the Liquidity Risk Model: No Bank Run Case 2 Figure 3: Ex Post Bank Run in the Baseline Model 3 Figure 4: Ex Post Bank Run in the Liquidity Risk Model 4

Post a Comment

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

*

x

Hi!
I'm Katy

Would you like to get such a paper? How about receiving a customized one?

Check it out